National Round Table on the Environment and the Economy
Canada
Contact Us
Help
Search
Canada Site

About Us

Media Room

Library

Home
Achieving a Balance
" " Energy &
Climate Change
" " Capital Markets
About
Documents
FAQs
Committee
Program Contact
   
" "Brownfields
Subscribe to NRTEE e-briefs
Email thisEmail this

 

© 2006

_
""
" "

Case Study on Fiscal Policy and Energy Efficiency
Economic Study

Prepared by
M.K. Jaccard & Associates


Please note that this version of the case study is slightly modified from the version previously available. The modification relates to a paragraph in Section 3.5 of Appendix B dealing with aluminium electrolysis technologies
.

June 4, 2004

Next »

3 Alternative Forecasts

3.1 The Use of Models to Estimate Energy Efficiency Potential

A variety of energy-economy models can be used to estimate how changes in the energy efficiency, fuel type or emission controls of technologies could lead to different levels of GHG emissions. Of these, those with detailed technological representation are most applicable to modelling the case studies in this NRTEE research agenda. Typically, in an energy efficiency analysis, technologies (boilers, light bulbs, electric motors) that provide the same energy service (heating, lighting, industrial motive force) are generally assumed to be perfect substitutes except for differences in their financial costs and their emissions of GHGs and other pollutants. When their financial costs (capital and operating) in different time periods are converted into present value using a social discount rate, many current and emerging technologies available for reducing GHG emissions appear to be profitable or just slightly more expensive relative to existing equipment. These analyses often show that substantial GHG emission reduction can be profitable or low-cost were these low-emission technologies to increase from their small market share to achieve market dominance. 16

Nevertheless, these types of analyses overlook the complexities of adopting energy-efficient technologies by focusing on a single, ex ante (anticipated) estimate of financial cost. 17An assessment of an alternative scenario that examines the adoption of energy efficiency by industry needs to explicitly acknowledge the “efficiency gap” issues highlighted in section 2.2. An energy-economy model that is behaviourally explicit will provide a more realistic estimate of decarbonization potential. A model also needs to be technologically explicit. In industry this means that the unique technologies, processes and technological interactions of that sector’s diverse sub-sectors should be adequately represented. It is also important that a model be integrated between supply and demand sectors because price feedbacks matter in terms of adjustments caused by technical change in one sector.

3.2 Development of Alternative Scenarios

These concerns have guided the development of the CIMS model. This model was used to develop the baseline forecasts in the Baseline Study, and is used in the Economic Study to develop the alternative scenarios.

CIMS was described in some detail in the Baseline Study (section 3.2). We focus here on the methodology for developing the alternative scenarios.

Methodology

The CIMS model allows the analyst to explore an “achievable” potential, rather than that which may be only technically feasible. Energy efficiency actions (as represented by technologies that produce less carbon emissions) are adopted in the model according to the technology competition step outlined in Step 3 of the CIMS simulation (section 3.2, Baseline Study). This competition seeks to represent firm purchasing decisions based not only on minimization of annualized life cycle costs, but also on performance preferences, cost hetereogeneity, option value and failure risks.

Simulating a carbon emission shadow price in the industrial sector sub-models in CIMS can indicate the emission reduction potential from energy efficiency actions. This methodology is based on the principle that the goal of decarbonization would drive the formulation of an alternative GHG scenario (as simulated by a shadow price for carbon), which would indicate what role energy efficiency investments could play in decarbonization amongst other options – fuel switching, reducing fugitive emissions, reducing process emissions, and CO2 capture and storage. Carbon abatement actions occur up to the specified marginal abatement cost for carbon.

Because CIMS describes energy services in flow models which show the sequence of activities required to generate particular products or services (see section 3.1, Baseline Study), efficiency actions can be modelled in an integrated way. This approach is important because as the literature on energy efficiency has consistently shown, a focus on individual energy efficiency actions in isolation will produce different estimates of efficiency potential and cost than will an integrated systems approach. Energy efficiency actions are often interrelated and only a systems approach can explore this interplay18.

For this study, two alternative forecasts, low carbon I and low carbon II, are produced by simulating two different shadow prices over a 25-year simulation period (2005-2030). In addition to applying this shadow price to the industry sector sub-models, we also apply the price to the electricity sector so that a carbon price can be reflected in the electricity price used to evaluate technology investment decisions in the industry sub-sector models.19 In both cases investment patterns and energy flows change from their baseline evolution to produce a forecast with lower carbon emissions. We model a price of $15/tonne CO2e in low carbon I, and $30/tonne CO2e in low carbon II to influence a shift in investment patterns in CIMS, which reflects relatively modest “achievable potential” that could be influenced by EFR policy.

Although the energy price and demand feedback functions are included in the simulation, we were requested not to incorporate the macro-economic feedback function in CIMS. This was done to maintain consistency with the other two decarbonization case studies. The NRTEE may use the outputs from the case studies as inputs to a macro-economic model at a later stage in its research program. This often creates methodological inconsistencies because of differences in macro-models and a technology-rich model, such as CIMS. An alternative would be to simulate this and other decarbonization actions/policies with CIMS.20

This project considers a longer timeline than is typically conducted in most GHG emission analysis (which has been focused on the Kyoto target of six to eight years). Emerging technologies have a greater ability to gain market acceptance in a 25-year time frame. In order to capture the long-term promotion of these technologies through R&D and commercialization support, we adjust the “intangible costs” in the model in the alternative scenarios to reflect a more targeted commercialization effort. These adjustments were made to the following technologies:

Table 3-1: Emerging Technologies

Sector Technology
Aluminum Inert anodes / Wetted cathodes
Chemicals New catalysts
Iron & steel Thin and strip slab casting
Iron & steel Direct-reduced iron
Industrial minerals Fluidized bed kilns
Pulp and paper High-intensity drying
Pulp and paper Black liquor gasification
Metals Hydrometallurgy (nickel)

3.3 Results / Discussion – Alternative Scenarios

Table 3-2 summarizes the results of the low carbon I and low carbon II scenarios relative to the scenario presented in the Baseline Study. The low carbon I and II scenarios result in GHG reductions of 46 Mt CO2e and 58 Mt CO2e by 2030. Though the shadow price doubles between the two scenarios (from a $15/t CO2e to a $30/t CO2e price), only 26% more reductions result from an increase in price. This non-linear relationship between the shadow price and emission reductions reflects the relative cost of actions that underly the results. 21

Direct emissions make up most of these emission reductions, though the response of indirect emissions to the imposition of a shadow price is stronger than the response of direct emissions (indirect emissions decline by 53-62% in 2030, while direct emissions only decline by 5-7%). Actions behind this strong indirect response include the greater adoption of cogeneration systems and actions that improve the overall efficiency of auxiliary motor systems.

Results for individual sub-sectors are shown in Tables 3-3 to 3-13. Only total emissions are shown (sum of direct and indirect). For each sector we show the relative trends in direct GHG intensities (t CO2e/GJ) and energy intensities (GJ/physical production) in each simulation. These indicators suggest the relative role of energy efficiency compared to fuel switching in the results. However, for some sectors these are not clearcut. For instance, changes in the energy intensity indicator also represent saved natural gas from leak programs (natural gas extraction sector), and changes in the GHG intensity indicator represent changes to process emissions (metal smelting, chemical products, iron and steel) and fugitive emissions (upstream oil and gas sectors, coal mining). In the chemical products and the pulp and paper sectors, total emissions decline in the low carbon I and II scenarios despite increasing energy consumption. This is due to the increased adoption of cogeneration, which results in increases in total energy, which offset by indirect emissions savings associated with cogenerated electricity.

Energy efficiency actions figure among a variety of different types of actions in the GHG reductions in each sub-sector. The upstream oil and gas sector, which is responsible for significant emission reductions in each time period, makes many reductions through actions that curtail fugitive emissions.22 The metal smelting and refining sector, petroleum refining, and iron and steel sub-sectors contribute the most emission reductions due to improved energy efficiency in the alternative scenario simulations.

The decarbonization potential described in the alternative scenarios are likely conservative based on the following.

  1. Neither operating and maintenance actions nor all industrial ecology relationships are included in this analysis.23
  2. Over a long forecast horizon, emerging technology options may see their capital costs decline through market deployment. Also, these technologies may become more attractive to firms as their prevalence in the economy increases. These factors are not incorporated into this analysis.
  3. Future radical technology innovation cannot be anticipated by the model. Rather, the model represents the greater deployment of current and emerging technologies (though some, such as direct reduced iron, represent radical innovation).

Employing higher carbon prices in the alternative scenario would result in more significant emission reductions, although cost-curve analysis using CIMS suggests that the potential for additional emission reductions diminishes past a shadow price of $50/tonne CO2e.24 Nevertheless, it is important to consider that higher shadow prices would potentially have a stronger effect in inducing technological innovation in low-carbon and energy-efficient technologies (through both radical and incremental innovation), increasing the potential for long-term decarbonization. Also, shifts would likely occur in the specific types of products produced by industry towards those requiring less carbon-intense inputs.

Table 3-2: GHG Emissions and Energy for Alternative Scenarios, Canada

  2000 2010 2020 2030
Total GHG Emissions
(Mt CO2e)
       
BAU 288 343 396 453
Low Carbon I 288 322 365 407
Low Carbon II 288 316 355 395
Direct GHG Emissions
(Mt CO2e)
       
BAU 237 307 358 407
Low Carbon I 237 292 339 386
Low Carbon II 237 293 335 378
Indirect GHG Emissions
(Mt CO2e)
       
BAU 50 36 38 46
Low Carbon I 50 29 26 22
Low Carbon II 50 23 20 17
Energy (PJ)        
BAU 4,239 5,030 5,783 6,579
Low Carbon I 4,239 4,822 5,537 6,298
Low Carbon II 4,239 4,818 5,497 6,232

Table 3-3: Emissions, Energy and Intensity Indicators, Chemical Products Sector

  2000 2010 2020 2030
Total GHG Emissions
(Mt CO2e)
       
BAU 24 26 32 38
Low Carbon I 24 21 25 31
Low Carbon II 24 21 25 30
Total Energy (PJ)        
BAU 236.7 272.9 327.8 398.5
Low Carbon I 236.7 287.4 352.6 433.8
Low Carbon II 236.7 281.6 346.9 433.4
GHG Intensity
(t direct CO2e / GJ)
       
BAU 0.08 0.09 0.09 0.08
Low Carbon I 0.08 0.09 0.09 0.09
Low Carbon II 0.08 0.09 0.09 0.09
Energy Intensity
(GJ / t chemical)
       
BAU 14.7 13.3 12.7 12.3
Low Carbon I 14.7 14.0 13.7 13.4
Low Carbon II 14.7 13.8 13.4 13.4

Table 3-4: Emissions, Energy and Intensity Indicators, Coal Mining Sector

  2000 2010 2020 2030
Total GHG Emissions (Mt CO2e)        
BAU 3.1 3.2 3.4 3.9
Low Carbon I 3.1 2.8 2.7 3.0
Low Carbon II 3.1 2.2 2.2 2.5
Total Energy (PJ)        
BAU 19.5 20.4 22.7 26.6
Low Carbon I 19.5 18.8 19.9 23.0
Low Carbon II 19.5 15.6 16.9 20.7
GHG Intensity (t direct CO2e / GJ)        
BAU 0.12 0.13 0.13 0.14
Low Carbon I 0.12 0.12 0.11 0.12
Low Carbon II 0.12 0.12 0.11 0.11
Energy Intensity (GJ / t coal)        
BAU 0.3 0.3 0.2 0.2
Low Carbon I 0.3 0.2 0.2 0.2
Low Carbon II 0.3 0.2 0.2 0.2

Note: Reductions in GHG emissions also occur through demand reductions (as a result of demand and supply feedbacks between the sub-models that demand coal and the coal mining sub-model).

Table 3-5: Emissions, Energy and Intensity Indicators, Industrial Minerals Sector

  2000 2010 2020 2030
Total GHG Emissions
(Mt CO2e)
       
BAU 14.4 15.8 18.4 22.7
Low Carbon I 14.4 14.6 16.6 20.6
Low Carbon II 14.4 14.7 15.2 18.2
Total Energy (PJ)        
BAU 79.7 84.8 97.9 120.5
Low Carbon I 79.7 81.3 92.8 114.7
Low Carbon II 79.7 81.5 89.1 108.0
GHG Intensity
(t direct CO2e / GJ)
       
BAU 0.17 0.18 0.18 0.18
Low Carbon I 0.17 0.18 0.18 0.18
Low Carbon II 0.17 0.18 0.17 0.17
Energy Intensity
(GJ / t clinker)
       
BAU 6.1 5.7 5.4 5.1
Low Carbon I 6.1 5.4 5.1 4.9
Low Carbon II 6.1 5.5 4.9 4.6

Table 3-6: Emissions, Energy and Intensity Indicators, Iron and Steel Sector

  2000 2010 2020 2030
Total GHG Emissions
(Mt CO2e)
       
BAU 18.1 19.0 20.9 23.9
Low Carbon I 18.1 18.4 19.7 22.2
Low Carbon II 18.1 18.4 19.6 22.1
Total Energy (PJ)        
BAU 250.9 266.6 288.0 320.4
Low Carbon I 250.9 252.7 261.3 281.3
Low Carbon II 250.9 253.1 260.8 280.0
GHG Intensity
(t direct CO2e / GJ)
       
BAU 0.07 0.07 0.07 0.07
Low Carbon I 0.07 0.07 0.07 0.07
Low Carbon II 0.07 0.07 0.07 0.07
Energy Intensity
(GJ / t steel)
       
BAU 15.2 14.3 13.7 13.5
Low Carbon I 15.2 13.5 12.4 11.8
Low Carbon II 15.2 13.5 12.4 11.8

Table 3-7: Emissions, Energy and Intensity Indicators, Mining Sector

  2000 2010 2020 2030
Total GHG Emissions
(Mt CO2e)
       
BAU 7.1 5.8 5.7 5.8
Low Carbon I 7.1 5.6 5.4 5.4
Low Carbon II 7.1 5.6 5.4 5.3
Total Energy (PJ)        
BAU 103.7 102.6 103.1 105.8
Low Carbon I 103.7 100.4 99.1 100.6
Low Carbon II 103.7 100.5 98.7 99.7
GHG Intensity
(t direct CO2e / GJ)
       
BAU 0.04 0.04 0.04 0.037
Low Carbon I 0.04 0.04 0.04 0.036
Low Carbon II 0.04 0.04 0.04 0.035
Energy Intensity
(GJ / t throughput)
       
BAU 0.4 0.4 0.4 0.4
Low Carbon I 0.4 0.4 0.4 0.3
Low Carbon II 0.4 0.4 0.4 0.3

Table 3-8: Emissions, Energy and Intensity Indicators, Natural Gas Sector

  2000 2010 2020 2030
Total GHG Emissions
(Mt CO2e)
       
BAU 73.2 75.3 86.1 98.7
Low Carbon I 73.2 66.3 74.4 86.0
Low Carbon II 73.2 66.2 73.8 84.5
Total Energy (PJ)        
BAU 1121.4 1194.7 1413.0 1663.7
Low Carbon I 1121.4 1046.2 1220.7 1461.6
Low Carbon II 1121.4 1044.4 1207.4 1431.4
GHG Intensity
(t direct CO2e / GJ)
       
BAU 0.05 0.05 0.05 0.05
Low Carbon I 0.05 0.05 0.05 0.05
Low Carbon II 0.05 0.05 0.05 0.05
Energy Intensity
(GJ / 1000m^3)
       
BAU 5.2 4.4 4.5 4.8
Low Carbon I 5.2 3.8 3.9 4.2
Low Carbon II 5.2 3.8 3.8 4.1

Table 3-9: Emissions, Energy and Intensity Indicators, Other Manufacturing Sector

  2000 2010 2020 2030
Total GHG Emissions
(Mt CO2e)
       
BAU 35.6 35.6 38.3 42.5
Low Carbon I 35.6 32.9 35.6 39.6
Low Carbon II 35.6 33.3 35.5 39.2
Total Energy (PJ)        
BAU 671.9 714.2 774.8 846.4
Low Carbon I 671.9 708.3 764.8 833.2
Low Carbon II 671.9 708.9 764.4 832.0
GHG Intensity
(t direct CO2e / GJ)
       
BAU 0.34 0.36 0.38 0.42
Low Carbon I 0.34 0.35 0.38 0.41
Low Carbon II 0.34 0.35 0.38 0.41
Energy Intensity
(GJ / $97 million)
       
BAU 5,314.9 4,486.0 3,935.9 3,953.7
Low Carbon I 5,314.9 4,448.4 3,884.9 3,892.0
Low Carbon II 5,314.9 4,452.6 3,883.2 3,886.2

Table 3-10: Emissions, Energy and Intensity Indicators, Petroleum Crude Extraction Sector

  2000 2010 2020 2030
Total GHG Emissions
(Mt CO2e)
       
BAU 55.1 100.0 121.7 135.9
Low Carbon I 55.1 104.7 124.1 132.2
Low Carbon II 55.1 99.4 119.0 129.2
Total Energy (PJ)        
BAU 273.7 858.5 1,136.5 1,334.0
Low Carbon I 273.7 827.1 1,104.2 1,305.6
Low Carbon II 273.7 834.7 1,093.5 1,282.5
GHG Intensity
(t direct CO2e / GJ)
       
BAU 0.19 0.12 0.11 0.10
Low Carbon I 0.19 0.12 0.11 0.11
Low Carbon II 0.19 0.12 0.11 0.11
Energy Intensity (GJ / m^3)        
BAU 2.4 4.2 4.7 4.1
Low Carbon I 2.4 4.1 4.5 4.0
Low Carbon II 2.4 4.1 4.5 4.0

Table 3-11: Emissions, Energy and Intensity Indicators, Petroleum Refining Sector

  2000 2010 2020 2030
Total GHG Emissions
(Mt CO2e)
       
BAU 19.9 21.9 25.1 29.1
Low Carbon I 19.9 21.8 24.7 28.4
Low Carbon II 19.9 21.8 24.5 28.1
Total Energy (PJ)        
BAU 310.0 288.3 327.3 364.9
Low Carbon I 310.0 287.8 325.8 370.8
Low Carbon II 310.0 287.6 325.5 370.5
GHG Intensity
(t direct CO2e / GJ)
       
BAU 0.06 0.08 0.08 0.08
Low Carbon I 0.06 0.07 0.08 0.08
Low Carbon II 0.06 0.08 0.08 0.08
Energy Intensity (GJ / m^3)        
BAU 3.4 2.8 2.9 3.0
Low Carbon I 3.4 2.8 2.8 2.9
Low Carbon II 3.4 2.8 2.8 2.9

Table 3-12: Emissions, Energy and Intensity Indicators, Pulp and Paper Sector

  2000 2010 2020 2030
Total GHG Emissions
(Mt CO2e)
       
BAU 19.7 18.5 21.2 26.3
Low Carbon I 19.7 15.2 16.8 20.3
Low Carbon II 19.7 14.6 14.7 17.0
Total Energy (PJ)        
BAU 901.2 934 986 1,068
Low Carbon I 901.2 929 1,007 1,100
Low Carbon II 901.2 928 1,005 1,101
GHG Intensity
(t direct CO2e / GJ)
       
BAU 0.01 0.01 0.02 0.02
Low Carbon I 0.01 0.01 0.01 0.01
Low Carbon II 0.01 0.01 0.01 0.01
Energy Intensity
(GJ / t product)
       
BAU 31.5 28.7 26.5 24.8
Low Carbon I 31.5 28.5 27.0 25.5
Low Carbon II 31.5 28.5 27.0 25.5

Table 3 13: Emissions, Energy and Intensity Indicators, Non-Ferrous Metal Smelting and Refining Sector

  2000 2010 2020 2030
Total GHG Emissions
(Mt CO2e)
       
BAU 17.2 20.8 22.8 25.6
Low Carbon I 17.2 18.9 20.3 22.0
Low Carbon II 17.2 18.8 19.9 21.3
Total Energy (PJ)        
BAU 269.4 290.5 302.6 320.3
Low Carbon I 269.4 282.1 286.6 296.3
Low Carbon II 269.4 281.7 285.2 293.9
GHG Intensity
(t direct CO2e / GJ)
       
BAU 0.06 0.06 0.06 0.06
Low Carbon I 0.06 0.06 0.06 0.06
Low Carbon II 0.06 0.06 0.06 0.05
Energy Intensity
(GJ / t product)
       
BAU 63.3 55.6 50.5 46.4
Low Carbon I 63.3 54.0 47.8 42.9
Low Carbon II 63.3 54.0 47.6 42.6

Next »